From: http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Global_Economy/KA22Dj03.html
THE
FOLLY OF INTERVENTION, Part 1
The
zero interest rate trap
By Henry C K Liu
John
Maynard Keynes formulated the phenomenon of absolute cash preference
in a distressed market as a liquidity trap
that can neutralize the stimulative effect of quantitative easing
(increasing the money supply by changing the quantity of bank
reserves) by the central bank.
Japan's two-decade-long
recession is a manifestation of a zero interest rate trap that can
also neutralize the stimulative effect of credit easing (lowering the
cost of credit) by the central bank.
Federal Reserve board
chairman Ben Bernanke, in the Stamp Lecture at London School of
Economics, London, England on January 13 this year, defined the
difference between quantitative easing and credit easing as
follows:
The Federal Reserve's approach to supporting credit markets is conceptually distinct from quantitative easing (QE), the policy approach used by the Bank of Japan from 2001 to 2006. Our approach - which could be described as "credit easing" - resembles quantitative easing in one respect: It involves an expansion of the central bank's balance sheet. However, in a pure QE regime, the focus of policy is the quantity of bank reserves, which are liabilities of the central bank; the composition of loans and securities on the asset side of the central bank's balance sheet is incidental. Indeed, although the Bank of Japan's policy approach during the QE period was quite multifaceted, the overall stance of its policy was gauged primarily in terms of its target for bank reserves. In contrast, the Federal Reserve's credit easing approach focuses on the mix of loans and securities that it holds and on how this composition of assets affects credit conditions for households and businesses.
Each in separate ways, the liquidity and the zero interest rate traps
together demonstrate the futility of
macroeconomic attempts to use both quantitative and credit easing by
the central bank to stimulate an economy contracting from excessive
debt and leverage.
A liquidity trap can be formed when
holders of cash seek safe haven from risk in a distressed market.
They rush to park cash in risk-free financial instruments until the
market stabilizes, causing short-term interest rates on top-rated
fixed-income investments to fall from market forces of supply and
demand. A low short-term rate in such a situation is the result and
not the cause of a slowing economy. Under such conditions, central
bank lowering of federal funds rate targets below that set by market
forces can have the effect of pushing investors towards higher risk
in search of better returns in a risk-averse market in which good
investment opportunities are in short supply.
Since central
bank power to set interest rates is unevenly concentrated on the
short term, a liquidity trap distorts the term
structure of interest rates which defines the expanding spread
between short-term and longer-term interest rates. This is because
the Federal Reserve's influence on the much larger outstanding
long-term credit market is less direct than the short-term credit
market, where the central bank has complete control for rates for
loans of short maturities.
Yet the Federal Reserve is
institutionally focused more on the long-term health of the monetary
system as compared to the Treasury, which is institutionally more
concerned with the short-term health of the financial sector. Thus to
achieve the Federal Reserves' long-term goal for the monetary system,
a stable interest rate regime is ideal. Milton Friedman and other
monetarist have long agreed on 3% as the most effective interest rate
with up to 6% structural unemployment for avoiding wide price
volatility and destructive business cycles.
The "risk
structure" of interest rates defines the rising risk premium for
a declining scale of credit ratings. Risk premium is defined as the
difference between the rate of return on risk-free government
securities and other financial instrument of higher risk. The higher
the risk, the larger is the compensatory risk premium. The risk
premium, which is calculated from both historical data and
forward-looking estimates, adjusts the required risk/reward ratio for
investments of different risk exposures.
On January 6, 2009, the
yield on one-month Treasuries was near zero while a year earlier it
was 3.2%. In one year, the Fed cut the short-term rate by nearly 320
basis points to stimulate the slowing economy. Again on January 6,
the yield on 10-year Treasuries was 2.5%, while 12 months earlier it
was 3.8%. In one year, the long-term rate fell only 130 basis points
from market forces, less than half of the short-term rate cut of 320
basis points by the Fed.
On January 6, the term structure between
federal funds and 10-year Treasury rates was 250 basis points. A year
earlier the term structure was only 60 basis points. The Fed had
pushed the short-term rate down further (by 190 basis points) than
the fall of the long-term rate from market forces, widening the
normal term structure of interest rates by 2.5 times. This means
significant future inflation was being seeded.
Risk/reward
ratio
In the 16th century, Chinese rice traders observed the
intricate relationships between opening, high, low and closing market
prices and represented them graphically using vertical bars which
came to be known nowadays on Wall Street as Japanese candlesticks
because Japanese traders learned it from their Chinese counterparts
and Western traders later learned the technique from Japan during the
Meiji reform era of 1868-1912.
Today, candlestick traders
look for recognizable patterns with repeating "highs" as
good probabilities for profitable trades. They do this by determining
entry and exit points to meet profit targets and stop loss targets.
These trading points can be located by looking at historical moving
averages, Bollinger bands, or other technical indicators to evaluate
probable support and resistance levels.
In the 1980s, John
Bollinger developed the Bollinger Bands as a technical analysis tool
from the concept of trading bands. Bollinger Bands can be used to
provide a relative definition of high and low and to measure the
highness or lowness of a price relative to previous trades. By
definition, prices are high at the upper band and low at the lower
band. This definition can enhance rigor in pattern recognition and is
useful in comparing price action to indicator movements to arrive at
disciplined trading decisions.
Some stock traders seek profit
by buying when price touches the lower Bollinger Band and selling
when price touches the moving average in the center of the bands.
Other traders buy when the price breaks above the upper Bollinger
Band and sell when the price falls below the lower Bollinger Band.
Options traders, most notably implied volatility traders, often sell
options when Bollinger Bands are far apart by historical standards,
and buy options when the Bollinger Bands are close together,
expecting volatility to revert back towards the average historical
volatility level. When the bands lie close together, a period of low
volatility in stock price is indicated; and when far apart, a period
of high volatility in price is indicated. When the bands have only a
slight slope and lie approximately parallel for an extended time, the
price of a stock will be found to oscillate up and down between the
bands as though in a channel.
As an illustration, a stock
with a per share entry price of $20.35 can be assigned by the trader
a profit target of $21.35 and a stop loss target of $19.85. The risk
of loss is $20.35 minus $19.85, or $0.50. The reward is $21.35 minus
$20.35, or $1. The trade is risking 50 cents to make $1, with a
risk/reward ratio of 1:2. The return on capital of $20.35 is around
20:1, or 5% for the open duration of the trade, which could be
minutes, hours, days or months. If the trade is closed out by the
stop loss target, the return on capital is negative 40:1, or -2.5%.
Trading and financing cost has not been included in the calculations.
A long open period will reduce the positive return on capital as
financing cost rises over time.
It is necessary to bear in
mind that rational quantitative trading models, while giving an
unemotional framework for decision making, are not guarantees for
achieving targets. Models are by definitions abstractions of reality,
which is infinitely more complex. One can fail rationally as well as
intuitively. Often, rationality can prolong the denial phase
unconstructively even when intuition suggests something is wrong.
There is another problem of modeling reality. Most model
builders assume reality to be rational and orderly. In fact, life is
full of misinformation, disinformation, errors of judgment,
miscalculations, communication breakdowns, ill will, legalized fraud,
unwarranted optimism, prematurely throwing in the towel, and so
forth. One view of the business world is that it is a snake pit. Very
few economic models reflect that perspective.
The risk-reward
ratio provides a non-intuitive quantitative evaluation of risk
decisions. It does not say anything about the qualitative evaluation
of the decision, which is the surmised probability of achieving the
profit target, which when missed, will produce a loss of $0.50 per
share plus transaction and financing cost. Price reward ratios are
merely quantitative justification for taking manageable risk. High
risk only means high probability of loss but it is not synonymous
with certainty of loss.
Probability/impact ratio
Good
management of risk must include a probability/impact ratio. A low
probability event with high impact is more dangerous or profitable
than a high probability event with low impact, which may fall into
the "not worth the bother" category unless it can be
exploited in large volume with high leverage. The net capital rule
created by the SEC in 1975 required broker-dealers to limit their
debt-to-net-capital ratio to 12-to-1. After the rule was exempted in
2004 for five big firms, many hedge funds increased their leverage to
40-to-1 to maximize profit by enlarging the risk profile.
Both
risk and profit magnified by leverage The five big investment
banking firms wanted for their brokerage units an exemption from the
1975 regulation that had limited the amount of debt they could take
on to $12 for every dollar of equity. The debt-to-net-capital ratio
exemption would unshackle billions of dollars held in reserve as a
cushion against potential losses on their investments and trades. The
released equity funds from higher leverage could then flow up to the
parent company, enabling it to speculate in the fast growing but
opaque world of mortgage-backed securities, credit
derivatives, and credit default swaps (a form of insurance for bond
holders), and other exotic structured finance instruments.
In
2004, the European Union, responding to financial globalization and
to attract profitable finance operations to financial centers in its
member nations, passed a rule allowing the European counterpart of
the US SEC to liberalize management of risk both for broker dealers
and their investment banking holding parents. In response, the SEC
instituted a matching voluntary program for broker-dealers with
capital of at least $5 billion, enabling the SEC to oversee both the
broker-dealers and the holding parents. Deregulation was being driven
by financial nationalism.
Ever since the Great Depression,
the US government has tried to limit the leverage available to
investors in the US stock market by maintaining margin requirements.
But regulators, led by former chairman of the Federal Reserve Alan
Greenspan, thought
financial innovation would be hampered and financial activity driven
to unregulated markets overseas if there were any attempts to impose
limits on leverage in the unregulated credit and capital markets.
After all, innovation was viewed as the driving force in US
prosperity. The global financial system embarked on a race to assume
more risk under a mentality of "if I don't smoke, somebody else
will".
This brave new approach, which all five
qualifying broker-dealers - Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers, Merrill
Lynch, Goldman Sachs, and Morgan Stanley - voluntarily adopted,
altered the way the SEC measured their capital. The five big firms
led the charge for the net capital rule change to promote financial
innovation, spearheaded by Goldman Sachs, then headed by Henry
Paulson, who two years later, would leave Goldman to become the
Treasury Secretary and until the departure of the George W Bush
administration this month had to deal with the global mess after
failing to secure government aid. Bear Sterns and Merrill Lynch had
been sold to big commercial banks and Goldman and Morgan Stanley have
turned themselves into regulated bank-holding companies. The age of
independent investment banks came to an end in the US.
Growth
of structured finance
Structured finance, the structuring of
financial needs for larger markets to generate greater financial
value, emerged at first as a means to profit from unlocking latent
value of conventional debt
through unbundling of risk through securitization, and to gain from
eliminating market inefficiency through arbitrage. It creates
financial value by facilitating the transfer unit risk to the credit
system through complex legal entities that shift liabilities off
balance sheet. Risk transfer through debt securitization leads to
degradation in underwriting standards, as liability is transferred to
counterparties or to market participants systemically.
Advances
in computerized trading enable the handling of large amounts of
market information at electronic speed to conduct profitable trades
to exploit market inefficiency to restore fundamental equilibrium.
The intellectual energy of structured finance came through spillovers
from advances in risk management in nuclear arms control during the
Cold War. Before long, with financial deregulation, quantitative
trading groups, known as quant shops, and hedge
funds, hoping to profit
from capitalizing on eliminating market inefficiency, were springing
up like mushrooms after a spring rain.
Also, risk management
needs by all institutions that have exposure to financial risk create
massive market demand for derivative instruments of all varieties and
complexities to transfer unit risk to systemic risk. This leads to
securitization of financial obligations to manipulate risk levels in
order to attract investors of varying risk appetite. With
increasingly sophisticated hedging against risk, investors begin to
assume higher tolerance for risk through hedging. Hedging then
transforms from a method of protection by reducing risk, to one of
achieving higher profit by assuming more risk. Risk is no longer
merely an index of danger; it becomes an index to command
compensatory returns. Risk changes from something to be avoided to
something that should be sought for those seeking higher returns.
Finance capitalism is built on a structure of risk.
Hedging
only transfers risk to other parties; it does not eliminate risk from
the system. Systemic risk rises as more unit risks are hedged. But
while unit risk is managed by resident risk managers, deregulation
reduced the role of systemic risk managers, traditionally market
regulators, which in the US are the Federal Reserve for banking
institutions and the Security Exchange Commission for equity markets.
Former Fed chairman 0Greenspan's argument in support for
deregulation is that innovation should not be inhibited and that self
interest of financial institutions would be sufficient to assure self
regulation. The logic is akin to the argument that if foxes were
given free run of chicken coops, self interest of the foxes would
regulate consumption of chickens to ensure a steady food supply. He
has since admitted that he had put too much faith in the
self-correcting power of free markets.
Seduced by fantasy
profit targets
The entire structured finance sector has been
seduced by fantasy profit targets driven by excess liquidity of cheap
money released by the central bank. These fantasy profit targets are
pushed even unrealistically higher by the under-pricing of risk due
to the ease with which entity risk has been passed onto
counterparties in the global credit system to get liabilities off the
balance sheets of funding intermediaries and underwriters.
Instead
of acting as responsible intermediaries between investors,
securitizing intermediaries and borrowers, investment banks while
acting as securitizing intermediaries, also became investors in
structured finance instruments they themselves invented and whose
risk has been under-priced and whose safety is dependent on the
performance of borrowers of poor credit ratings and record.
Fantasy
profit targets have permeated the entire credit market because risk
has been pushed unrealistically low by spreading it to a great number
of counterparties in a daisy chain. When a few counterparties in the
daisy chain defaulted, it impacted the credit ratings of all parties
in the global daisy chain, requiring additional compensatory
collateral, placing the entire daisy chain in an unenviable position
of undercapitalization. The opaqueness of the daisy chain makes it
impossible to locate and strengthen the weak links and the whole
system comes crashing down from undercapitalization.
The
fear factor
A fantasy profit target cannot be justified
merely by low risk, particularly if the alleged low-risk assessment
itself is a fantasy. There is no mileage in risking even one penny
for an impossible dream. Pricing of risk is a judgment call based on
confidence on likelihood of gain, the reverse of which is fear of
loss. The fear factor usually faces a rising threshold in a bull
market and declining bar in a bear market in reverse direction to a
required risk-reward ratio. The greater the fear, the higher would
the risk-reward ratio be required. At some point, the fear factor can
push the required risk-reward ratio to infinity when risk aversion
overrides any and all reasonable profit targets. That is the point
when markets seize.
Historical data suggest that a 100 basis
point (1%) increase in federal funds rate has been associated with 32
basis point change in the 10-year bond rate in the same direction.
Many convergence trading models based on this ratio are used by hedge
funds.
The failure of long-term rates to increase as
short-term rates were raised by the Fed in late winter 2003 can be
explained by the expectation theory of the term structure that links
market expectation of the future path of short-term rates to changes
in long-term rates, as St Louis Fed president William Poole pointed
out in a speech to the Money Marketeers in New York on June 14, 2005.
The market simply did not expect the Fed to keep the short-term rate
high for extended periods under then current bullish conditions. The
upward trend of short-term rates was expected by the market to
moderate or reverse direction as soon as the economy slowed.
The
failure of long-term rates to fall as short-term rates were cut by
the Fed to near zero in December 2008 can be explained by the fear
factor and by the uncertain direction of the purchasing power of the
dollar in the future.
Zero short-term rate can raise
systemic risk
A liquidity trap can also raise the risk
premium as market appetite for risk wanes and investors flee towards
safety. But a zero short-term interest rate trap set by the central
bank can distort the historical term structure by abnormally widening
the gap between short-term and long-term rates as long-term rates
fail to fall with the short-term rate because of a rising spread in
risk premiums.
This distortion can increase
systemic risk by tempting investors to engage in term interest
arbitrage, by borrowing at a near-zero short term rate to invest in
higher-yielding long-term instruments with even normal risk premiums.
The re-pricing of short-term risk was a root cause of the
1997 Asian financial crisis and it was again a root cause of the 2007
credit crisis a decade later. Monetarism had
not banished the business cycle; it merely extended the length of the
boom phase by making the eventual bust more painful.
A
liquidity trap, together with a zero interest rate trap, can combine
to lead to a structural under-pricing of risk, followed by a
subsequent overshoot of the risk premium from a rising fear factor,
and lead to a systemic failure of the short-term credit market. In
August 2008, all debts that matured in 30, 90 or 120 days could not
be rolled over at previous rates, or as the fear factor escalated, at
any interest rate.
Risk is inherently dangerous even if it is
priced appropriately to reflect realistic market conditions. A
healthy does of risk aversion is indispensable for the survival of
financial capitalism, which thrives only on prudent risk-taking, not
suicidal heroic risk abuse. Yet under-pricing of risk driven by
excess liquidity released by the central bank over long periods to
stimulate economic activities, the basic strategy of monetarism, will
implode as a systemic crisis at the end of the day as surely as the
sun will set.
Central banking, democracy and monetary
policy
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 gave the Federal
Reserve authority and responsibility for setting monetary policy,
which guides central bank actions to influence the availability and
cost of money and credit to help promote national economic goals.
Since the founding of the country, full employment has never been
part of the US national economic goal. From the nation's beginning,
during the pioneering days, the US faced a persistent labor shortage.
In the agricultural South, the labor shortage problem was solved by
the institution of slavery. During the age of capitalist
industrialization, the industrial North solved the labor shortage
problem with immigration after 1830 from the laboring class in
Europe. Until then, the US did not have a working class, or an
unemployment problem.
The winning of independence by the US
from Britain in 1782 was accompanied by gloomy predictions that the
new nation would not succeed in creating a stable central authority
to replace the British Crown and would quickly dissolve into anarchy.
It was to the great credit of the founding fathers that they were
able to create a new democratic republican government that would
combine freedom with order, and local self-government with national
unity. The achievement was the more remarkable in view of the deep
socio-economic and ideological conflicts among the American people on
contradictions between individualism and collectivism, democracy and
oligarchy, conservatism and liberalism, and agrarianism and
mercantilism.
The democratic ideal was
represented early on by Sam Adams, Patrick Henry and other Sons of
Liberty. Among constitution drafters, democratic ideals were
represented by Thomas Jefferson. In the 1820s, democratic
politics found expression in the new Democratic Party headed by
Andrew Jackson. These early democrats believed that government should
be controlled by the people and that its power should be strictly
limited and its economic policy should aim at protecting the
interests of the average citizen rather than the wealthy elite.
This democratic attitude was natural to economic conditions
of abundance of land and self-development opportunities that formed
the virgin political canvas on which to paint a new city on the hill
from 18th century liberalism. Before the formation of economic
classes, the US representative democracy was based on geographic
regions focusing on sectional interests rather than class interests.
This early liberalism was fundamentally different from 19th century
liberalism and 21st century neo-liberalism under which the working
class, while emerging as the majority of the population, was
systemically underrepresented politically as control of all political
machinery was captured by the moneyed class, as predicted by Alexis
de Tocqueville, who warned in his Democracy in America
published in 1836 that the loss of "general equality of
condition" would threaten equality in American society.
Alexander Hamilton was the spokesman of
the American aristocratic movement, representing large landowners,
foreign trade merchants and international financiers. Hamilton,
a forerunner supply-sider, believed that
wealth can be created only by the energetic financial elite, who,
through their superior intelligence and character, are natural
entrepreneurs and innovators and so can better mobilize the ignorant
and undisciplined masses for high national purpose than the contented
agricultural landed gentry.
Politically, Hamilton thought the
people could not be trusted with power and that majority
rule without strong minority rights would
lead to confiscation by the undeserving poor of the wealth created by
the deserving rich. Hamilton favored a strong central
government controlled and run for the public good by a well-born,
educated elite of principle and property.
Thomas J DiLorenzo
in his new book, Hamilton's Curse: How Jefferson's Arch Enemy
Betrayed the American Revolution - and What It Means for America
Today, argues that, regarding the stipulation that policies must
promote "the public good", "no government policy can
be said to be for 'the public good' unless it benefits every member
of the public". More often than not, the "public good"
turns out to mean good only for special interests. The argument put
the test for legitimate government intervention on the populist
effect of government policies.
Hamilton
rationalizes state intervention on the basis of high national
purpose. His view of government control of the economy is more
appropriate for emerging economies, such as the US economy in the
1860s, the Japanese economy in the 1950s or the Chinese economy
today. Henry Clay's "American System" after the War of 1812
took Hamilton's elitist program of economic nationalism away from the
upper class and offered it to the masses by making federal authority
the champion of the people, rather than a captured machine for narrow
sectional interests.
Through representative democracy as
advocated by Jefferson, Clay promoted measures designed to strengthen
the young nation, enhancing its economic independence from foreign
economic and financial dominance with protective tariffs, and
promoted national unity by developing a reciprocal relationship
between agriculture and industry and through the establishment of a
nation bank to finance domestic development.
Daniel Webster,
representing New England internationalist shipping interests in
Congress, opposed Clay's populist economic nationalism. Clay's ideas
of economic nationalism are similar to Chinese economic policy today,
albeit adjustments need to be made regarding the difference in
historic conditions and political culture in the two countries. (See
US-CHINA:
QUEST FOR PEACE - Part 1: Two nations, a world apart, Asia Times
Online, December 9, 2003.)
Economically, while all Americans
in the mainstream believe in the protection of private property by
the state, Hamilton advocated the
concentration of wealth in the hands of those who will profitably use
it to build a strong nation, and that it not be distributed widely as
advocated by believers of economic democracy. Modern-day neo-liberals
are not Hamiltonians, in that they willingly compromise economic
nationalism in support of empire-building globalization in the name
of free trade.
Hamilton's idea reflected the need of a new,
young nation of rich undeveloped resources for capital formation in a
world beginning to enter the industrial capitalist age. In the 17th
and 18th centuries, the agricultural economy of the US faced a labor
shortage that gave rise to the institution of slavery. The agrarian
South prospered until challenged by the capitalist industrial North.
The Civil War settled more than the socioeconomic issue of
slavery. It set the US economy irreversibly on the path of industrial
capitalism. After 1850, early industrialization solved the labor
shortage problem by attracting immigration from the underprivileged
masses of Europe who formed the beginning of a laboring class, a
large segment of the population whose main economic function was to
provide labor to an industrial economy. The opening of the West
brought about servitude immigration from China, which was in decline
under conditions not much more liberal than slavery.
As the
process of industrialization in late 19th century reduced demand for
labor through mechanization while immigration continued as an
established policy, unemployment became a major socioeconomic issue
in the US. The end of slavery after the Civil War also added to an
oversupply of wage-earners in a not-so-free labor market.
Unemployment has since become a structural component in capitalism as
fundamental as interest charges on the use of money.
During
the age of feudalism, finance was not an arena for the elite in
Europe. The US, founded only in 1776, did not experience a feudal
economy. In the age of industrial capitalism, industrialists were in
control of the US economy, while relying on passive financial
institutions for capital. Henry Ford (1863-1947) was disdainful of
bankers. Industrialists and inventors such as Ford and Thomas Edison
(1847-1931) did not consider themselves as capitalists, even though
they operated under capitalism.
As finance capitalism
replaced industrial capitalism, financiers wrestled control of the
economy from the industrialists. Standard Oil and General Motors were
financial trusts built around economic sectors through acquisition of
companies to form monopolies. Financiers such as JP Morgan and John D
Rockefeller were trust builders, not industrialists. Financial
engineering, a euphemism for financial manipulation, emerged as the
center for profit in which the aim of economic activity became that
of making profit to provide return on capital, rather than producing
goods to satisfy consumer needs.
To allow more capital
formation, financial capitalism disconnects profit from fair return
on production cost to what the money market will bear. Excess profit
requires low wages and leads inevitably to overinvestment in relation
to market demand. On the observation of this relationship, Karl Marx
formulated his concept of surplus value. The monetization of surplus
value became the basis of capital formation. As capital assumed
dominance over labor, finance became the core of capitalism.
Overcapacity resulting from overinvestment combines with
stagnant market demand resulting from low wages and structural
unemployment to cause recurring crises in market capitalism, known as
business cycles. After the Great Depression of the 1930s, social
security introduced as part of the New
Deal created a new reservoir of
wealth in pension
funds of workers. In World War
II, war demands soaked up all overcapacity and wage-price equilibrium
was established to facilitate war production.
With the growth
of pension funds, capital came increasingly from forced savings of
the working masses. Yet control of capital continued to stay in the
hands of the financial elite. While entrepreneurship
flowered democratically through social mobility and openness, it took
almost two centuries after its founding, until after the end of World
War ii, before the US would admit children of poor families into
finance professions, mostly due to the GI bill in support of
education for returning World War II veterans. Large numbers of Wall
Street leaders today owed their opportunity to education provided by
the GI Bill.
While the entrance to the arena of wealth
management is now more democratic, the institutions that operate the
machinery of wealth manipulation remain fundamentally biased in favor
of capital against labor, even though overcapacity from
overinvestment has become clearly a structural problem that can only
be solved by workers being allowed to get a fairer share of the
wealth they essentially create.
Central banking, in its
adherence to monetarism that aims to protect the value of money at
the expense
of fair wages, is a strategic bastion against a much-needed new
financial order to address this imbalance between the labor theory of
value and the theory of marginal utility of supply and demand in a
market economy. The modern economy requires fair spreading of wealth
for the common good by maintaining a balance between supply and
demand.
Exchange rate and monetary policy
Like the
federal funds rate target, currency exchange rate is not a product of
market forces. It is always, directly or indirectly, the product of
national policy. Although exchange rate policy has become a crucial
component of monetary policy after the 1971 collapse of the Bretton
Woods regime of fixed exchange rates based on a gold-pegged dollar at
$35 per ounce, the Treasury retains responsibility for setting
exchange rate policy as a matter of national economic security. On
exchange rate issues, the Fed follows policies set by the Treasury
with no questions asked.
The Federal Reserve controls three
traditional tools of monetary policy: 1) open market operations, 2)
the discount rate and 3) bank reserve requirements. Using these three
tools, the Federal Reserve influences the demand for, and supply of,
balances that depository institutions hold at federal reserve banks,
and in this way alters the federal funds rate, the interest rate at
which depository institutions lend balances at the Federal Reserve to
other depository institutions overnight.
Of these three
tools, the discount rate and bank reserve requirements regulate banks
as market intermediaries; only open market operations interact
directly in the market to keep the federal funds rate on target as
set by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Changes in
the federal funds rate trigger a chain of market events that affect
other short-term interest rates, foreign exchange rates, long-term
interest rates, the amount of money and credit, a range of economic
variables, including employment, output, and prices of goods and
services and ultimately the market value of derivative instruments.
The board of governors of the Federal Reserve System is
responsible for the discount rate and reserve requirements, which
regulate liquidity in the banking system but not liquidity in the
non-bank credit markets, such as commercial paper markets and
structured finance markets. The FOMC is responsible for open market
operations, which involve purchases and sales of US Treasury and
federal agency securities. Open market operations are the Federal
Reserve's principal tool for implementing monetary policy in the
market directly.
The FOMC consists of 12 members - the seven
members of the board of governors of the Federal Reserve System; the
president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which carries out
open market operations; and four of the remaining 11 Reserve Bank
presidents, who serve one-year terms on a rotating basis. Non-voting
Reserve Bank presidents attend the meetings of the committee,
participate in the discussions, and contribute to the committee's
assessment of the economy and policy options.
The FOMC holds
eight regularly scheduled meetings per year to review economic and
financial conditions, determine the appropriate stance of monetary
policy, and assess the risks to its long-run goals of price stability
and sustainable economic growth. The chairman can call emergency
meetings at any time at his/her discretion, through conference calls
by phone if necessary.
The short-term objective for open
market operations has varied over time, ranging from maintaining a
desired quantity of reserves to affect the money supply to
maintaining a desired price for funds set by the federal funds rate
target.
During the 1980s, the Fed under chairman Paul Volcker
adopted a "new operating method" as a therapeutic shock
treatment for Wall Street, which had been spoiled fearless by the
brazen political opportunism of Arthur Burns, Volcker's predecessor
during the Nixon-Ford era. Wall Street had lost faith in the Fed's
political will to control inflation after Nixon's misuse of
Keynesianism to bypass the unappetizing choice of "guns or
butter" to fund his "guns and butter"
fantasy with fiscal deficits.
Volcker's new operating
method concentrated on managing monetary aggregates to levels deemed
appropriate for a given state of the economy and let them dictate
federal funds rate swings to be facilitated by Fed open market
operations. For 1980, the inflation momentum meant a federal funds
rate target within a range from 13-19% was needed in the context of
double-digit inflation.
This new operating method was an
exercise in "creative uncertainty" to shock the financial
market out of its complacency about the Fed's tradition of
interest-rate stability and gradualism. The market had developed a
habitual expectation that even if the Fed were forced by inflation
trends to raise interest rates, it would not permit the market to be
volatile, lest the political wrath from both the White House and
Congress should threaten its existence by abolishing it. Banks could
continue to create money through lending as long as they could
profitably manage the gradual rise in rates, foiling the Fed's policy
objective of slowing the growth of the money supply to contain
inflation.
Volcker's new operating method reversed this
traditional mandate of the Fed, which, as a central bank, was
supposed to be responsible for maintaining orderly markets, meaning
smooth, gradual changes in interest rates. The new operating method
was an attempt to induce the threat of
short-term pain to stabilize long-term inflation expectations.
The reversal was necessary because the market had come to expect the
Fed only gradually to raise interest rates to keep
even an unbalanced economy from collapsing.
Targeting
a steady money supply generates large sudden swings in short-term
interest rates, which produces unintended shifts in the real
economy that then feed back into new demand for money. The process
has been described as the Fed acting as a monetarist dog chasing its
own tail.
Unlike the Keynesian formula of deficit financing
to reduce unemployment in a down cycle, the Fed's easy-money approach
since the Nixon administration had been to channel the funny money to
the rich, who needed it least, rather than to the poor, who would
immediately spend it to sustain aggregate demand to moderate the down
phase of the business cycle.
This supply-side, easy-money
approach led to an economy of permanent overcapacity, with idle
plants unable to produce goods profitably for lack of consumer demand
due to low wages. Say's law, that supply creates its own demand, is
inoperative unless there is full employment, which sound money deems
undesirable. Supply-side theory is cooked by its own success
requiring its own failure to bring about.
Greenspan's
measured-pace gradualism
Alan Greenspan, who succeeded
Volcker at the Fed on August 11, 1987, re-adopted a measured-paced
interest-rate policy to revert to the Fed's tradition of gradualism.
The trouble with a measured-paced interest-rate policy in a
debt-driven economy of overcapacity is that the
debt cancer is spreading faster than the gradual doses of medical
radiation can handle. Yet fatality is a poor tradeoff for the
avoidance of hair loss from radiation. Greenspan's measured pace
represented a lack of political courage to acknowledge that it
is preferable by far for the finance sector to take a huge haircut
preemptively than for the whole economy to collapse later.
This lack of political courage is still evident.
Moral hazard
is increased unless risk-takers in the finance sector are made to
bear the consequences of their actions and not be allowed to pass the
pain from excessive risk-taking on to the economy at large. Thus any
government bailout with public money should be directed towards
saving the economy directly and not to save
wayward institutions that aim to ensure their own undeserved survival
by holding the economy hostage. (See Greenspan,
the Wizard of Bubbleland, Asia Times Online, September 14, 2005.)
Senator Richard Shelby, the senior Republican member of the
Senate Banking Committee, said the George W Bush administration's
effort to avoid an imminent meltdown of the US financial system could
end up costing taxpayers $1 trillion. Yet after spending a good part
of that huge sum, the economy lost 2.5 million jobs in 2008 with
524,000 jobs lost in December alone. The Bush administration this
month has handed over to the Barack Obama administration a sick
economy in need of intensive care, with 7.2% unemployment, above the
6% structural tolerance, with 11.1 million unemployed workers.
Goldman Sachs projects the unemployment rate to hit 9% by the end of
2009.
The Obama economic team has proposed an $800 billion
stimulus package that promises to create 4 million new jobs in two
years. That comes to $200,000 of stimulus spending to create one new
job. Still, with 2.5 million jobs expected to be lost each year,
Obama's stimulus plan of creating 2 million new jobs each year still
leaves 500,000 newly unemployed workers.
To give jobs to
today's 11.1 million unemployed, Obama's stimulus plan would need to
be around $2.5 trillion, plus another $200 billion every year for new
workers entering the economy to keep the nation fully employed.
Common sense would suggest there's got to be a better way. This is
not an argument for non-intervention, but an argument against
ineffective intervention that insists on rescuing people in financial
distress by first rescuing the distressed institutions that put them
there.
One of the reasons while the New Deal was less than
effective in fighting unemployment was that Franklin D Roosevelt
was reluctant to implement direct relief programs. Keynes
wrote to Roosevelt in February 1938 to criticize his program for
insufficient relief spending.
On the other hand, the Obama
campaign for the presidency reportedly spent $105,599,963 in the
first two weeks of October 2008, which came to $293,000 an hour. So
spending $200,000 to create one new job is not as outrageous as it
sounds. As they say, it's all relative.
The Federal Funds
rate target
From its low of 1% set on June 25, 2003, the
federal funds rate target was raised by the Fed to 5.25% on June 29,
2006, in 17 steps of 25 basis points each. The Greenspan Fed had kept
the rate at 1% for one whole year before raising it on June 24, 2004
to 1.25%. Greenspan raised the fed funds rate another 25 basis points
to 4.50% on January 31, 2005, his last day in office.
Ben
Bernanke assumed office as chairman of the Fed on February 1, 2006,
and continued the upward path to raise the fed funds rate target by
25 basis points to 4.75% on March 28, to 5.00% on May 10, to 5.25% on
June 29 and kept it there until September 18, 2007, some eight weeks
after the credit market seized in July.
The Bernanke Fed then
began lowering the federal funds rate target on September 18, 2007 in
11 steps, with three steps cutting by 50 basis points and two steps
cutting by 75 basis points, until December 16, 2008 when the rate was
lowered to a range between 0% to 0.25%, an effective zero rate.
The
Fed has exhausted its interest rate ammunition since the fed funds
rate cannot go below zero. From then on, the Fed has to use
"unconventional" tools to rescue the financial market, such
as nationalization by other names. The New York Fed on January 5 this
year began buying mortgage-backed securities (MBS) guaranteed by
Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and Ginnie Mae as part of a $500 billion
program that equals a ninth of the $4.5
trillion agency MBS market.
Already stunned by the
Fed-arranged rescue of Bear Stearns by JP Morgan Chase on March 14,
2008, after only narrowly avoiding collapse, investors abruptly
exited short-term markets after Lehman Brothers collapsed and filed
for bankruptcy protection on September 15. Lehman did so after the
government refused to take responsibility for losses on some of the
firm's most troubled real-estate assets, something the government
agreed to do when JP Morgan Chase bought Bear Stearns to save it from
a bankruptcy filing in March.
While offering to help Wall
Street organize another shotgun marriage for Lehman, both Fed
chairman Bernanke and Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, being
sensitive to earlier criticism over the Bear Stearns rescue, declared
publicly that they would not again put taxpayer money at risk simply
to prevent a private institution such as Lehman from collapse. The
message marked a major reversal in government strategy established in
the Bear Stearns rescue.
It now remained unclear if the
government had adopted firm rules of the game to draw the firm line
on intervention. It became clear to the market that the piecemeal,
patchwork, case-by-case fire fighting approach of the Fed and the
Treasury without an overall strategy would do little to stabilize
market turmoil. The government has no overall plan for stopping the
spreading fire storm with an effective strategic fire break. Instead,
it appeared to be running around to put out fires in isolated
institutions as they started to burn.
Paulson, supported by
Bernanke, was sensitive to criticism that the Bush administration had
already gone too far ideologically merely a few weeks before the
presidential election in which Republicans, already hard-pressed by a
two unpopular and unending foreign wars, were also put on the
defensive on the economic front, first by underwriting the takeover
of Bear Stearns in March and by the far bigger bailout of Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac announced on July 13.
Accusations of
enlisting socialism to be the undertaker of market capitalism were
becoming vocal from conservatives, who claimed that once the
socialist genie is out of the bottle, it would be impossible to put
it back. While that assertion is on target, the assertion that the US
is falling into socialism is not. What the US is doing is enlisting
state capitalism to save market capitalism.
The disclosure
that Merrill Lynch, now owned by Bank
of America, had suffered a $21.5
billion operating loss as the value of mortgage-backed assets plunged
in the last three months of 2008 came as BofA secured a $138 billion
bail-out from the US government.
BofA finalized an $18.8
billion all-share takeover of Merrill in early January 2009, received
a $20 billion capital infusion and a backstop on $118 billion of
troubled assets. BofA told the government in December 2008 that it
would not be able to close the deal without help. Shares in BofA,
which reported a $2.4 billion loss in a quarter marred by Merrill's
disastrous performance, fell nearly 14%.
Citigroup underlined
the depth of banks' problems by reporting an $8.3 billion net loss,
its fifth consecutive quarter of loss. The troubled financial group
suffered nearly $28 billion in write-downs and loan loss provisions
in Q4 2008 as the price of mortgage securities plummeted. Citi's loss
for 2008 was more than $18 billion. The company confirmed its plan to
isolate some $800 billion worth of unwanted assets and businesses
into a non-core unit called Citi Holdings.
At his January 13,
2009 London School of Economics Stamp Lecture: "The Crisis and
the Policy Response", Bernanke suggested measures of
nationalization of the banking system while denying the
characterization. Banks have transformed from being "too big to
fail" to being "too big to rescue
by non-nationalization means". In the case of Citigroup, the
continuing losses have so far become so big, with still more to come,
that it approaches the mathematically impossible for the Fed to
inject enough capital into it without taking a majority stake, thus
squeezing out or at least diluting existing shareholders. The new
ground rules laid down by the incoming Obama economic team for the
final half of the $700 billion bailout fund, the Troubled Asset
Relief Program (TARP), called for government control over bank
operations such as dividend payments
and executive compensation.
Some have misleadingly suggested
that the government's approach of nationalizing the banks harks back
to Andrew Jackson's closing of the Second Bank
of the United States in 1841. But in
fact the equivalent of Jackson's move would be to close the Federal
Reserve System.
The First Bank
of the United States was founded by Treasury Secretary
Alexander Hamilton in 1791 with a charter for 20 years to handle the
financial needs and requirements of the central government of the
newly formed United States. Its mission was to establish financial
order, clarity and precedence in and of the newly formed United
States, to establish domestic and foreign credit
for the new nation and to resolve the chaotic currency left to the
Continental Congress immediately prior to and during the
Revolutionary War.
The bank proposal was supported by
Northern merchants but viewed with suspicions by Southern
plantationers, whose economy did not need a centralized bank. The
major controversy centered around the bank's incorporation as a
private institution with public powers.
Secretary of State
Thomas Jefferson argued that the bank violated traditional property
laws and that Hamilton's proposal was against both the spirit and
letter of the country's constitution and its relevance to
constitutionally authorized powers was weak. To this day, the Federal
Reserve, established in 1913, having transformed its mission from a
national bank to support the development of the nation to a central
bank to preserve the value of money, continues to be a
private institution owned by member banks with
public power granted by Congress.
By the early 1830s,
populist president Andrew Jackson had come to be thoroughly
antagonistic to the Second Bank of the United
States because of its fraud and corruption on behalf of special
interests. Jackson ordered an investigation, which established
that the bank was "an instrument of political corruption and a
threat to American liberties" and "beyond question that
this great and powerful institution had been actively engaged in
attempting to influence the elections of the public officers by means
of its money". A replay of Jackson's
killing of the Second Bank of the United States would be Obama
abolishing the Federal Reserve System.
The $300
billion aid package of Citigroup in November 2008 and the additional
$150 billion for Bank of America on January 15, 2009, relating to
losses by BofA acquisition of Merrill Lynch, are being presented
publicly not as bank nationalization moves but, in a fest of
accounting gymnastics, as insurance programs for toxic bank assets.
Reversing the Treasury's previous approach of investing
billions of taxpayer dollars only in "healthy" bank
recapitalization against toxic assets, the Fed is now guaranteeing
the banks' non-performing liabilities, which may well turn out to
cost taxpaying much more money if such guarantees have to be covered
by Fed insurance.
Instead of merely bailing out healthy banks
by investing taxpayer dollars in exchange for
banks' preferred shares, which would receive a regular
dividend and include warrants that could benefit the government
should bank stocks rise in price, but letting bank shareholders take
part of the loss, the Fed now has committed
itself to bailing out the entire credit system against losses, to the
disadvantage of taxpayers.
The Citigroup deal covered
$300 billion in toxic assets, with Citigroup agreeing to absorb the
first $29 billion in losses, the Treasury then absorbing up to $5
billion, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation then absorbing up
to $10 billion and finally the Federal Reserve lending Citigroup at
low interest rates for the value of the remaining toxic assets.
The
Bernanke Fed is now proposing putting a bank's impaired assets into a
separate new "bad" bank to free the bank from the need to
set aside more reserves for further losses. This would prevent the
bank's common shareholders from being wiped out by the government.
NEXT: No exit for emergency nationalization
Henry C K Liu is chairman of a New
York-based private investment group. His website is at
http://www.henryckliu.com.
(Copyright 2009 Asia Times Online
(Holdings) Ltd. All rights reserved. Please contact us about sales,
syndication and republishing.)